Economist's View: Exchange Rate Models "Not as Bad as You Think"

リンク: Economist's View: Exchange Rate Models "Not as Bad as You Think".

Charles Engel says there has been progress on exchange rate models since Meese and Rogoff's famous finding that the models are no better than a random walk at predicting the out-of-sample evolution of exchange rates:

Exchange-Rate Models, by Charles Engel, NBER Reporter, Fall 2006: Recent research that my co-authors and I have undertaken, as well as related research by other NBER researchers, suggests that theoretical models of foreign exchange rates are "not as bad as you think." ...

Should Exchange Rate Models Out-predict the Random Walk Model? For many years, the standard criterion for judging exchange rate models has been, do they beat the random-walk model for forecasting changes in exchange rates? This criterion was popularized by the seminal work of Meese and Rogoff.[1] They found that the empirical exchange rate models of the 1970s that seemed to fit very well in-sample tended to have a very poor out-of-sample fit. ...[S]ubsequent work has evaluated exchange rate models by the criterion of whether they produce forecasts with a lower mean-squared error than the simple random walk forecast of no change. Mark's (1995) paper was important in reviving interest in empirical exchange rate models.[2] He found that the models were helpful in predicting exchange rates at long horizons. Subsequent work has cast doubt on whether exchange rates can be forecast at long horizons, so there is a weak consensus that the models are not very helpful in forecasting...

West and I question the standard criterion for judging exchange rate models.[3]

Many exchange rate models can be written so that they explain the exchange rate as a weighted sum of current "fundamentals" (such as money supplies, prices, output levels) and the expected future value of the exchange rate. The models actually put relatively little weight on the current fundamentals and much more weight on expectations. ... So, the models imply that innovations in the current fundamental may not have a large effect on the exchange rate.

This type of model can be solved forward to express the exchange rate as the expected present discounted value of current and future fundamentals. West and I demonstrate the following result for this class of models: if the fundamentals are integrated of order 1 (that is, their first difference is stationary), and the discount factor is close to one, then the exchange rate will approximately follow a random walk. One important implication of this result is that the standard criterion used in evaluating exchange rate models -- can the models out-forecast a random walk? -- is not useful here. The Engel-West result shows that the models actually imply that the exchange rate will approximately follow a random walk. Evidence that they do not perform better than a random walk in forecasting exchange rates cannot be taken as evidence against the models. ...

Other Means of Evaluating Exchange Rate Models ...[H]ow closely linked are the "observed" fundamentals to exchange rates? West and I[5] note that, since the exchange rate is supposed to be the expected present value of current and future fundamentals, perhaps the exchange rate is useful in forecasting some of the observed fundamentals. In that paper we indeed find (weak) evidence to confirm the hypothesis. Note that since the exchange rate also moves with news about future "unobserved" fundamentals, we should not expect it to be an excellent forecaster of the observed fundamentals alone.

How much of the volatility of exchange rates is accounted for by the "observed fundamentals"?

A separate criticism of the present value models of exchange rates is that the volatility of the present value is smaller in practice than the volatility of the exchange rate. That is actually the opposite of the way it should be. Calculating the present value requires making a forecast of future fundamentals. Researchers do not have all the information that the markets use in constructing forecasts, so their forecasts should have higher variance than the markets'. ...

West and i[6] demonstrate that, again when the discount factor is near one, the variance in innovations of the discounted sum of current and expected future fundamentals calculated by the researcher with his inferior information set is approximately equal to the variance in innovations of the present value when forecasts are based on the market's information.

With that result in hand, we are able to ask how the conditional variance of the discounted present value of expected observed fundamentals compares with the conditional variance of the exchange rate. The answer is that the observed fundamentals for a few commonly used exchange rate models account for, on average, about 40 percent of exchange rate volatility. While this still means that either left-out fundamentals account for much of the volatility, or that there is excess volatility, it is encouraging relative to previous work. It no longer seems so hopeless that an improved exchange rate model can account for exchange rate volatility.

Indeed, perhaps such a model can be developed out of the new line of macroeconomic research that has emphasized that monetary policy is set as a Taylor rule: interest rates are set to respond to inflation, the output gap, and perhaps other economic variables. West and I[7] provide some favorable evidence for such models. We[8] show that the Taylor-rule model, when expressed as a present value relationship, has a modest positive correlation with the actual real dollar/DM rate over the 1979-98 period. An interesting implication of the model is that an increase in expected future inflation in a country actually causes the currency to appreciate. The reason for this is that under the Taylor rule, the policymaker raises interest rates more than the increase in expected inflation. This aspect of the model plays an important role in tracking the actual dollar/DM rate...

Since expectations are the prime mover of exchange rates and expectations change only when there is news, we can ask whether exchange rates respond to news in the way the models predict. That is exactly the exercise undertaken by Clarida and Waldman.[12] As noted above, Taylor-rule models imply that a country's currency will appreciate when there is news of higher inflation. Clarida and Waldman examine announcements of inflation rates, compared to survey expectations of what the announced inflation rate will be. They find that when the announcement is that inflation is unexpectedly high, the currency tends to appreciate. That relationship is strong in countries that explicitly target inflation and is weaker or non-existent in countries that do not target inflation.

Conclusions and Implications It is difficult to evaluate exchange rate models. Models of asset prices in general are difficult to test because asset price changes are driven by changes in expectations of future fundamentals. It is hard for the researcher to measure expectations. The problem is compounded in the case of exchange rates because we know that there are some components of the fundamentals that we cannot directly observe. Still, the recent research first refutes the notion that the failure of the models to predict exchange rate changes is strong evidence against the models. And, there is some favorable evidence: exchange rates contain news about future fundamentals; they are not so excessively volatile as the literature once accepted; Taylor-rule models show some promise; and, exchange rates respond to news in the way the models predict.

In closing I turn to my paper with Devereux.[13] which explores the implications of the fact that exchange rates respond primarily to news about future fundamentals. An overly brief synopsis of the main lesson from the new Keynesian economics is that monetary policy should aim - to the extent it can - to eliminate the distortions introduced by sticky nominal prices. Ideally, monetary policy should try to reproduce the outcome that would be achieved if nominal prices were flexible. We show that, in an open economy there is a problem... [R]elative prices - the prices of goods set in one currency relative to those set in another currency - will change when the nominal exchange rate changes. The problem is that those relative prices are changing when there is news about future fundamentals (monetary and real) that drive the nominal exchange rate. If goods prices were flexible, then relative goods prices would not be influenced by news about the future that is driving the nominal exchange rate. This is a distortion in relative prices caused by nominal price stickiness. Our paper argues that, since most of the variation in exchange rates comes from news about these future fundamentals, most exchange rate variation generates inefficient relative price movements. We argue that there is a case for monetary policy to target unexpected changes in nominal exchange rates in addition to targeting inflation.


[1] R. A. Meese and K. S. Rogoff, 1983, "Empirical Exchange Rate Models of the Seventies: Do They Fit Out of Sample?" Journal of International Economics 14 (February): pp. 3-24.

[2] N. C. Mark, 1995, "Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: Evidence on Long-Horizon Predictability," American Economic Review 85 (March): pp. 201-18.

[3] C. Engel and K. D. West, "Exchange Rates and Fundamentals," NBER Working Paper No. 10723, September 2004, published in Journal of Political Economy 113 (June 2005): pp. 485-517.

[4] J. Y. Campbell and R. J. Shiller, "Cointegration and Tests of Present Value Models," NBER Working Paper No. 1885, June 1988, published in Journal of Political Economy 95 (October 1987): pp. 1062-88.

[5] C. Engel and K.D. West, "Exchange Rates and Fundamentals," op. cit.

[6] C. Engel and K. D. West, "Accounting for Exchange Rate Variability in Present Value Models when the Discount Factor is Near One," NBER Working Paper No. 10267, February 2004, published in American Economic Review, Papers & Proceedings 94 (May 2004): pp.119-25.

[7] C. Engel and K. D. West, "Exchange Rates and Fundamentals," op. cit., and C. Engel and K. D. West, "Taylor Rules and the Deutschemark-Dollar Real Exchange Rate," NBER Working Paper No. 10995, December 2004, published in Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 38 (August 2006): pp. 1175-94.

[8] C. Engel and K. D. West, "Taylor Rules…" op. cit.

[9] N. C. Mark, "Changing Monetary Policy Rules, Learning, and Real Exchange Rate Dynamics," NBER Working Paper No. 11061, January 2005.

[10] P. Bacchetta and E. van Wincoop, "Can Information Heterogeneity Explain the Exchange Rate Determination Puzzle?" NBER Working Paper No. 9498, February 2003, published in American Economic Review 96 (June 2006): pp. 552-76.

[11] K. Kasa, T. B. Walker, and C. H. Whiteman, "Asset Prices in a Time-Series Model with Perpetually Disparately Informed, Competitive Traders," manuscript, Department of Economics, Simon Fraser University, June 2006.

[12] R. Clarida and D. Waldman, "Is Bad News about Inflation Good News for the Exchange Rate?" in J. Y. Campbell, ed., Asset Prices and Monetary Policy, University of Chicago Press, forthcoming.

[13] M. B. Devereux and C. Engel, "Expectations and Exchange Rate Policy," NBER Working Paper No. 12213, May 2006.

Posted by Mark Thoma on November 15, 2006 at 01:50 PM in Academic Papers, Economics, International Finance, International Trade | Submit to Digg | Add to Del.icio.us | Reddit This | Permalink

TrackBack

TrackBack URL for this entry:
http://www.typepad.com/t/trackback/6842065

Listed below are links to weblogs that reference Exchange Rate Models "Not as Bad as You Think":

Comments

When the yardstick by which models are evaluated cannot be beat, choose a different yardstick.

A bit more seriously, I view this in the same way that I view research into the underlying fat-tailed distribution of equity prices: it may perhaps be useful at some point, not for predicting prices (traders will be disappointed) but for offering information about the underlying mechanism for generating asset pricing information.

Posted by: Richard | Nov 15, 2006 3:13:17 PM

Foreign exchange is as close to casino capitalism as you can get. When only around 5% of the daily FX volume of about $1.6 trillion is associated with trade flows, the rest is speculation. Witness the weak yen at a time when the Japanese export machine is in high gear. How can it be so when Japanese exports as a percentage of GDP have only now exceeded Plaza Accord-era highs?

If you thought the DJIA reaching all-time highs as GDP slows made no sense, wait till you get to FX fantasyland.

Posted by: Emmanuel | Nov 15, 2006 3:55:00 PM

Short Engel...
Exchange rate models are pretty bad, but their not absolutely, incredibly hopeless.
(Condemn with faint praise).

Posted by: reason | Nov 16, 2006 1:21:30 AM

can we take from this that it may be possible to arbitrage between a basket of good in one country and the currency of another?

Posted by: adam | Nov 16, 2006 10:54:37 AM

Post a comment